Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Recent Developments in Intellectual Property and Antitrust ..., Lecture notes of Property Law

In the United States, it is our ambition to foster both innovation and commercialization that serves as common ground for our intellectual ...

Typology: Lecture notes

2021/2022

Uploaded on 09/12/2022

ringostarr
ringostarr ๐Ÿ‡ฌ๐Ÿ‡ง

4.7

(12)

314 documents

1 / 11

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
Recent Developments in Intellectual Property and Antitrust Laws in the United States
Remarks of Maureen K. Ohlhausen
Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission
Interaction of IP and Antitrust: A US-China Comparative Perspective
George Washington University Law School
June 17, 2013
Good morning. It is a pleasure to be here today and update you on some recent
developments at the intersection of the intellectual property and antitrust laws in the United
States.
1
Since our nationโ€™s inception, innovation has been the wellspring of American prosperity.
From the first flight by the Wright Brothers, Thomas Edisonโ€™s electric light bulb, the first
general-purpose electronic computer at the University of Pennsylvania, and the interconnection
of the world through the Internet, modern America stands on the shoulders of intellectual giants.
But surely, those geniuses also owe us lawyers a great deal โ€“ or rather, they owe another group
of geniuses โ€“ the drafters of our Constitution. Our founders instilled in us the belief that novel
ideas are valuable property and that an inventor should have certain rights, including to be able
to exclude others from using his or her property and practicing his or her invention. The Federal
Circuit has noted that without the right to exclude โ€œthe express purpose of the Constitution and
Congress, to promote the progress of the useful arts, would be seriously undermined.โ€
But innovation is only half the equation of our nationโ€™s success. It is the other half โ€“
commercialization โ€“ that turns new ideas into wealth and social prosperity. And just as
๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ๎˜ƒ
1
My remarks today reflect only my opinions; I am not speaking for the Commission or any other Commissioner.
United States of America
Federal Trade Commission
pf3
pf4
pf5
pf8
pf9
pfa

Partial preview of the text

Download Recent Developments in Intellectual Property and Antitrust ... and more Lecture notes Property Law in PDF only on Docsity!

Recent Developments in Intellectual Property and Antitrust Laws in the United States Remarks of Maureen K. Ohlhausen Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission Interaction of IP and Antitrust: A US-China Comparative Perspective George Washington University Law School June 17, 2013 Good morning. It is a pleasure to be here today and update you on some recent developments at the intersection of the intellectual property and antitrust laws in the United States.^1 Since our nationโ€™s inception, innovation has been the wellspring of American prosperity. From the first flight by the Wright Brothers, Thomas Edisonโ€™s electric light bulb, the first general-purpose electronic computer at the University of Pennsylvania, and the interconnection of the world through the Internet, modern America stands on the shoulders of intellectual giants. But surely, those geniuses also owe us lawyers a great deal โ€“ or rather, they owe another group of geniuses โ€“ the drafters of our Constitution. Our founders instilled in us the belief that novel ideas are valuable property and that an inventor should have certain rights, including to be able to exclude others from using his or her property and practicing his or her invention. The Federal Circuit has noted that without the right to exclude โ€œthe express purpose of the Constitution and Congress, to promote the progress of the useful arts, would be seriously undermined.โ€ But innovation is only half the equation of our nationโ€™s success. It is the other half โ€“ commercialization โ€“ that turns new ideas into wealth and social prosperity. And just as

(^1) My remarks today reflect only my opinions; I am not speaking for the Commission or any other Commissioner.

United States of America

Federal Trade Commission

innovation requires intellectual property protection, commercialization requires a level playing field free from anticompetitive duress, which requires vigilant antitrust protection. In the United States, it is our ambition to foster both innovation and commercialization that serves as common ground for our intellectual property and antitrust laws. As the FTC and DOJ observed in their 2007 IP Report, the antitrust and intellectual property laws โ€œshare the same fundamental goals of enhancing consumer welfare and promoting innovation [,]... work[ing] in tandem to bring new and better technologies, products, and services to consumers at lower prices.โ€^2 Nonetheless, there is an obvious tension between offering an inventor the right to exclude competitors from practicing an invention and fostering free and open competition in the market. The White House, federal courts, federal agencies, and private parties have been negotiating the frontier between competitive markets and strong intellectual property rights. At the FTC, we have been active in the debate on these issues generally, and particularly as they relate to standard essential patents, or SEPs, and the role of patent assertion entities, or PAEs, in the market. For my part, I believe the best way to navigate this terrain is to aspire to transparency, predictability, and fairness in all our actions at the FTC. This philosophy about governance has led me to dissent in several important decisions by the FTC in the past year. Standard Essential Patents Letโ€™s begin with standard essential patents, which have received a lot of attention lately. A patent is considered standard essential when it is declared or incorporated into an industry standard by a standard-setting body, thereby subsequently requiring manufacturers to license the patent for any technology that implements the standard. For example, a router maker that wants its routers to interoperate with most other wireless devices on the market cannot do so lawfully (^2) U. S. DEP โ€™ T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM โ€™ N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS : PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION http://www.ftc.gov/reports/innovation/P040101PromotingInnovationandCompetitionrpt0704.pdf. at 1 (2007), available at

order, or an injunction issued in district court, to โ€˜hold upโ€™ or demand higher royalties or other more costly licensing terms after the standard is implemented than could have been obtained before its [intellectual property] was included in the standard.โ€ I agreed with my fellow Commissioners that SEP hold-up is a theoretical possibility that the ITC or a court should consider in the analysis, but in keeping with my philosophy of transparency, predictability, and fairness, I broke with the other Commissioners when it came to two recent FTC enforcement actions on this issue. In the first matter, Robert Bosch GmbH (Bosch) , 3 the agency investigated a proposed acquisition by Bosch that raised competitive concerns in the market for certain automotive air conditioning repair equipment. During the course of the investigation, FTC staff uncovered evidence indicating that the acquired company, SPX Service Solutions (SPX), had sought injunctive relief against competitor firms that were interested in licensing certain SPX patents that may have been standard-essential and that SPX allegedly had offered to license on RAND terms.^4 The FTC settled this matter with Bosch, requiring Bosch to divest certain assets to address the proposed merger.^5 To address the alleged patent-related conduct, the FTC required Bosch, first, to agree not to seek injunctions on its standard-essential patents against parties that are willing to license such patents, and, second, to license those patents on a royalty-free basis.^6 In the second matter, the FTC investigated and ultimately entered a settlement with Google and its recently acquired subsidiary, Motorola Mobility.^7 As in Bosch , the FTC alleged that Google and Motorola violated Section 5 of the FTC Act โ€“ but not the antitrust laws โ€“ by

(^34) In re Robert Bosch GmbH, FTC File No. 121-0081. http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/1210081/121126boschanalysis.pdf. Id. , Analysis of Agreement Containing Consent Orders to Aid Public Comment, at 4 (Nov. 26, 2012),^ available at (^56) See id. at 3-4. 7 See id.In re Motorola Mobility LLC and Google Inc., FTC File No. 121-0120.^ at 4-5.

seeking injunctive relief against competitors that were willing to license certain standard- essential patents that Motorola had agreed to license on RAND terms through its participation in several standard-setting organizations.^8 In Google , the remedy imposed by the FTC was more complex than the flat prohibition on seeking injunctive relief imposed in Bosch. Rather, the FTCโ€™s consent order established a multi-step process that Google must go through before it is permitted to seek injunctive relief on its standard-essential patents.^9 In my dissents in the Bosch and Google matters, I took issue with, among other things, the lack of transparency and guidance that these decisions provided patent holders and others subject to our jurisdiction.^10 In particular, I raised concerns about the FTC enforcing Section 5 of the FTC Act without giving enough guidance about the relationship between that statutory provision and the antitrust laws, including the Sherman and Clayton Acts. Without this guidance, it is unclear what the term โ€œunfair method of competitionโ€ means or how the Commission will use its prosecutorial discretion to enforce Section 5. The lack of clarity in the FTC Act makes it even more important that we provide meaningful limiting principles to application of Section 5. A related point I raised in my Bosch and Google dissents is that one of the effects of those decisions was to create conflict between the FTC and other federal institutions.^11 The first is between the FTC and the ITC and federal courts, since the net result of our order is to prohibit

(^8) See id. , Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to Aid Public Comment, at 3-6 (Jan. 3, 2013), available at http://ftc.gov/os/caselist/1210120/130103googlemotorolaanalysis.pdf. (^9) See Analysis of Proposed Consent Order to Aid Public Comment, supra note 8, at 6-8. (^10) See In re Robert Bosch GmbH, FTC File No. 121-0081, Statement of Commissioner Maureen K. Ohlhausen, at 3- 4 (Nov. 26, 2012) [hereinafter Ohlhausen http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/1210081/121126boschohlhausenstatement.pdf; Bosch Statement], available at In re Motorola Mobility LLC and Google Inc., FTC File No. 121-0120, Dissenting Statement of Commissioner Maureen K. Ohlhausen, at 1-3 (Jan. 3,2013) [hereinafter Ohlhausen Google Dissent], available at http://ftc.gov/os/caselist/1210120/130103googlemotorolaohlhausenstmt.pdf. (^11) See Ohlhausen Bosch Statement, supra note 10, at 1-2; Ohlhausen Google Dissent, supra note 10, at 5-6.

ability of SEP holders to seek injunctions. 15 In my view, the majority did this in each case with little, if any, evidence that the patent holder agreed to waive this right when it participated in the standard-setting process. As I said earlier, most SSOs have not memorialized their FRAND terms and do not expressly prohibit seeking injunctions for SEPs. Moreover, in Bosch , the FTC required Bosch to grant royalty-free licenses on its patents as a remedy for seeking injunctions on its potential SEPs.^16 No matter how good our intentions, my concern is that our actions, if not properly explained, may send a message to our foreign counterparts that we do not place a very high value on intellectual property rights, which is clearly inconsistent with the appreciation for IP rights that we typically hold in the United States. Let me share with you an example of what I mean. Recently, I was in China attending a conference and meeting with Chinese competition officials. At the conference, I heard people claim that the United States has a well-established essential facilities doctrine, which is not exactly correct. In addition, it was suggested that when read in light of this doctrine, the FTCโ€™s Google decision implies that a SEP is an essential facility and an unreasonable refusal to license that SEP constitutes monopolization. It was further suggested that the best remedy for monopolization with a SEP would be compulsory licensing because permitting more parties to use the SEP would facilitate competition.

This is not a correct reading of relevant U.S. law or, in my opinion, of the FTCโ€™s decision in Google. This sort of misinterpretation is troubling on two levels. First, it undercuts the value of intellectual property rights and gives our counterparts abroad the misperception that we (^15) See In re Robert Bosch GmbH, FTC File No. 121-0081, Decision and Order, at 13-14 (Nov. 26, 2012), available at LLC and Google Inc., FTC File No. 121-0120, Decision and Order, at 6-12 (Jan. 3, 2013), http://www.ftc.gov/os/caselist/1210081/121126boschdo.pdf; In re Motorola Mobility available at http://ftc.gov/os/caselist/1210120/130103googlemotorolado.pdf. (^16) See Bosch D&O, supra note 15, at 13.

support wide application of compulsory licensing, which is completely incorrect. Second, if these misperceptions about our SEP enforcement actions here in the U.S. are actually implemented elsewhere in the world, the resulting harm to patent rights would create serious disincentives for investment in research and development and harm innovation.

Patent Assertion Entities Let me turn now for a few minutes to another major topic, patent assertion entities. A patent assertion entity, or PAE, is typically understood to mean a firm that owns patents but does not practice them, and that did not contribute to the research and development of those patents. The business model for many PAEs is to broadly assert and litigate the patent claims and thereby derive licensing and other revenues. Let me give you a few facts for context: ๏‚ท Nearly 5,000 patent lawsuits were filed in 2012; this is up from roughly 2500 in 2010.^17 ๏‚ท It has been estimated that PAE-generated revenue cost defendants and licensees $29billion in 2011 โ€“ 400% more than in 2005. 18 ๏‚ท As of December 1, 2012, PAEs brought roughly 60% of patent infringement lawsuits for the year. This is up from 45% in 2011 and just 19% in 2006.^19 ๏‚ท PAEs make 100 or more demands for each lawsuit filed.^20 ๏‚ท Studies show that NPE/PAEs buy and litigate the patents of small companies (50%) and individual inventors (28%) more than the patents of others.^21 This means they may serve a procompetitive benefit of protecting the little guy in monetizing patents. Other studiesshow, however, that the targets of PAE lawsuits are more often than not small companies on whom the impact is potentially more harmful.^22 ๏‚ท Studies have also shown that the legal costs exceed the settlement 90% of the time.^23 ๏‚ท Finally, another recent study showed that PAEs lose 92% of the time when litigated totrial on the merits. 24

(^1718) Executive Office of the President, Patent Assertion and U.S. Innovation, June 2013, at 5 [hereinafter PAE Report]. Economics Research Paper No. 12-34, 2012); FTC Chairman Leibowitz, Opening Remarks at Patent AssertionJames Bessen and Michael J. Meurer,^ The Direct Costs from NPE Disputes^ (Boston Univ. School of Law and Entity Workshop (Dec. 10, 2012) at 3. (^19) Colleen Chien, Patent Assertion Entities (Presentation at 2012 FTC/DOJ PAE Workshop) (Dec. 2012) at 23, available at (^20) Id. at 25. http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/workshops/pae/presentations/290073.pdf. (^2122) Id. at 47. 23 Id.Id.^ at 49-52.at 68. (^24) John. R. Allison, Mark A. Lemley, & Joshua Walker, Patent Quality and Settlement Among Repeat Patent Litigants , 99 Geo. L. J. 677, 694 (2011).

The FTC and DOJ have engaged in advocacy and education to determine the nature and scope of this problem. In 2011, the FTC held an intellectual property workshop (the Evolving IP Marketplace) and issued a report of its findings, including with respect to PAEs and the possibility for them to engage in patent hold up. And, just this December, the DOJ and FTC held a joint PAE workshop at which many scholars and market participants discussed the issues and potential solutions. We received a number of good comments, which we are currently studying to determine an appropriate course of action. The FTC also is advocating for regulatory change, including greater transparency through registration of real parties in interest. In 2003, the FTC recommended a more streamlined review process for granted patents that was incorporated into the America Invents Act, which Congress passed in 2011.^28 The DOJ and FTC recently submitted comments to the PTO in support of a proposal to require additional notice of the real party in interest for patent transfers and assignments. At a minimum, requiring the identification of the ultimate parent entity of the patent holder will facilitate greater efficiency in licensing.^29 It also could help avoid inadvertent infringement, which studies show is a significant problem because it makes the implementer potentially more vulnerable to rent extraction by a PAE. Although I generally support the FTCโ€™s efforts in examining the PAE issues and advocating for greater clarity and certainty in the patent system, I still have questions about whether this is a competition law problem or whether it is a problem in the patent system itself. One recent study indicates 82% of PAE defendants were sued for infringing software patents.^30 Another study estimates that it is five times more likely a software patent will be the subject of a

(^28) F ED. TRADE C OMMโ€™ N, TO P ROMOTE I NNOVATION : THE P ROPER B ALANCE OF COMPETITION AND P ATENT LAW AND (^29) F ED P OLICY. TRADE at 7 (2003); Leahy-Smith America Invents Act, Pub. L. No. 112-29, 125 Stat. 284-341 (2011). C OMMโ€™ N, THE E VOLVING IP MARKETPLACE at 17 (Mar. 2011), available at http://www.ftc.gov/bc/workshops/ipmarketplace/. (^30) PAE Report, supra note 17, at 5.

lawsuit as a chemical patent.^31 It is even worse for business method patents, which are roughly fourteen times as likely to end up in litigation.^32 This suggests to me that we are experiencing a problem in how to adequately define strong patents in terms of their nonobviousness, novelty, or other characteristics, which may not necessarily be a competition law problem. As is probably obvious from what I have said about Google/SEPs and Bosch , as well as my philosophy of transparency, predictability, and fairness, I would be very cautious about expanding Section 5 competition law liability to attach to basic claims of infringement by PAEs. Only where there is some evidence of additional conduct by a PAE that tends for instance to undermine the patent process or that falls within a recognized exception to Noerr like sham or repetitive litigation would I be compelled to intervene. But, as with SEPs and other issues at the frontier of the intellectual property laws and competition policy, I am still evaluating these issues and will continue to refine my position on the nature of this problem and the appropriate remedy. Thanks very much.

(^3132) Id. Id.