Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Problem Set 6 for Econometric Methods | EC 228, Assignments of Economics

Material Type: Assignment; Professor: Baum; Class: Econometric Methods; Subject: economics; University: Boston College; Term: Fall 2009;

Typology: Assignments

2009/2010

Uploaded on 02/24/2010

koofers-user-e87
koofers-user-e87 🇺🇸

10 documents

1 / 5

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
BOSTON COLLEGE
Department of Economics
EC 228 02 Econometric Methods
Fall 2009, Prof. Baum, Ms. Phillips (TA), Ms. Pumphrey (grader)
Problem Set 6
Due Thursday 19 November 2009
Total Points Possible: 120
Problem 10.6
(i) (5 pts) Given the formula for δj=γ0+γ1j+γ2j2, we substitute into
the original equation to get
yt=α0+γ0zt+ (γ0+γ1+γ2)zt1+ (γ0+ 2γ1+ 4γ2)zt2+
(γ0+ 3γ1+ 9γ2)zt3+ (γ0+ 4γ1+ 16γ2)zt4
which we can rearrange in terms of the γ’s as follows:
yt=α0+γ0(zt+zt1+zt2+zt3+zt4)+
γ1(zt1+ 2zt2+ 3zt3+ 4zt4) + γ2(zt1+ 4zt2+ 9zt3+ 16zt4)
(ii) (5 pts) Now we simply define 3 new variables x0, x1, x2as follows:
x0=zt+zt1+zt2+zt3+zt4
x1=zt1+ 2zt2+ 3zt3+ 4zt4
x2=zt1+ 4zt2+ 9zt3+ 16zt4
Then we can substitute these into our equation from part (i) and run
OLS on:
yt=α0+γ0x0+γ1x1+γ2x2
(iii) (5 pts) To see how many restrictions we have imposed, notice that
our original equation had six parameters: α0, δ0, δ1, δ2, δ3, δ4while our
new equation from part (ii) has 4 parameters: α0, γ0, γ1, γ2. So we
are imposing 6-4=2 restrictions. You could test the validity of these
restrictions using an F test with 2 and n-6 degrees of freedom.
Problem 10.7
(i) (5 pts) Since petis increasing, but (pet1pet) and (pet2pet) are
fixed, then we know that both pet1and pet2must also be increasing
at the same amount.
1
pf3
pf4
pf5

Partial preview of the text

Download Problem Set 6 for Econometric Methods | EC 228 and more Assignments Economics in PDF only on Docsity!

BOSTON COLLEGE

Department of Economics EC 228 02 Econometric Methods Fall 2009, Prof. Baum, Ms. Phillips (TA), Ms. Pumphrey (grader) Problem Set 6 Due Thursday 19 November 2009 Total Points Possible: 120

Problem 10.

(i) (5 pts) Given the formula for δj = γ 0 + γ 1 j + γ 2 j^2 , we substitute into the original equation to get yt = α 0 + γ 0 zt + (γ 0 + γ 1 + γ 2 )zt− 1 + (γ 0 + 2γ 1 + 4γ 2 )zt− 2 + (γ 0 + 3γ 1 + 9γ 2 )zt− 3 + (γ 0 + 4γ 1 + 16γ 2 )zt− 4 which we can rearrange in terms of the γ’s as follows: yt = α 0 + γ 0 (zt + zt− 1 + zt− 2 + zt− 3 + zt− 4 )+ γ 1 (zt− 1 + 2zt− 2 + 3zt− 3 + 4zt− 4 ) + γ 2 (zt− 1 + 4zt− 2 + 9zt− 3 + 16zt− 4 )

(ii) (5 pts) Now we simply define 3 new variables x 0 , x 1 , x 2 as follows: x 0 = zt + zt− 1 + zt− 2 + zt− 3 + zt− 4 x 1 = zt− 1 + 2zt− 2 + 3zt− 3 + 4zt− 4 x 2 = zt− 1 + 4zt− 2 + 9zt− 3 + 16zt− 4 Then we can substitute these into our equation from part (i) and run OLS on: yt = α 0 + γ 0 x 0 + γ 1 x 1 + γ 2 x 2

(iii) (5 pts) To see how many restrictions we have imposed, notice that our original equation had six parameters: α 0 , δ 0 , δ 1 , δ 2 , δ 3 , δ 4 while our new equation from part (ii) has 4 parameters: α 0 , γ 0 , γ 1 , γ 2. So we are imposing 6-4=2 restrictions. You could test the validity of these restrictions using an F test with 2 and n-6 degrees of freedom.

Problem 10.

(i) (5 pts) Since pet is increasing, but (pet− 1 − pet) and (pet− 2 − pet) are fixed, then we know that both pet− 1 and pet− 2 must also be increasing at the same amount.

(ii) (5 pts) The long-run propensity is defined as the change in gf r when pe increases permanently. So we can examine this change by increasing pet− 2 , pet− 1 , pet by the same amount. Then we can see from the original equation, that gf r is predicted to increase by δ 0 + δ 1 + δ 2 = θ 0 , which is our LRP.

Problem C10.

(i) (15 pts) Define y1979 if year > 1979; so it is a dummy with 0 for years 1948-1979 and 1 for 1980-2003. Then run regression from eq. 10.15. The coefficient on y1979 is 1.559 which is significant at the 1 percent level. This allows us to conclude that, ceteris paribus, after 1979 the interest rate on 3-month t-bills was 1.55 percent higher. So we can conclude that the regime change towards targeting the short-term interest rate increased this interest rate.

Problem C10.

(i) (5 pts) While the time trend variable is significant at the 1 percent level, none of the other variables are significant, even at the 20 percent level.

(ii) (5 pts) Conducting a joint F test for all other variables besides the time trend yields an F statistic with 6 and 123 dfs and a resulting probability of .7767. Therefore, we fail to reject the joint significance of all other variables besides the time trend.

(iii) (5 pts) We add dummies for February through December then run the regression from part i again. Then we can conduct a joint F test on the month dummies to determine the presence of seasonality. We get an F-stat of .85 with a p-val of .5943. Therefore, we fail to reject the absence of seasonality. Adding the month dummies does change the sign of the point estimates on lgas and lrtwex from positive to negative; however, it doesn’t change the lack of significance of any of the explanatory variables besides time. Some of the standard errors decrease in absolute value while others increase.

(ii) (5 pts) The estimated equation is

rsp̂ (^500) t = 18. 84 +. 036 pcipt− 1. 36 i (^3) t (3.27) (.129) (.54)

n = 557, R^2 =. 012. A one percentage point increase in industrial production growth is pre- dicted to increase the stock market return by .036 percentage points (a very small effect). On the other hand, a one percentage point increase in interest rates decreases the stock market return by an estimated 1. percentage points.

(iii) (5 pts) Only i3 is statistically significant with t-statistic ≈ -2.52.

(iv) (5 pts) The regression in part (i) has nothing directly to say about predicting stock returns because the explanatory variables are dated contemporaneously with rsp500. In other words, we do not know i (^3) t before we know rsp (^500) t. What the regression in part (i) says is that a change in i3 is associated with a contemporaneous change in rsp500.

Problem C10.

(i) (5 pts) Using browse beltlaw spdlaw we can see that the belt law was introduced in the 61st month of observation, or January 1986. We can see that the speed limit law was introduced in the 77th month of observation, or May 1987.

(ii) (5 pts) Using a linear time trend and the 11 monthly dummies for February to December, we get an estimate on the coefficient of the time trend as .0027 percent with a t-stat of 17.06, meaning that accidents are significantly increasing over time. The coefficient on t gives the average monthly increase in total accidents. So accidents are growing at (12 ∗ .275) = 3.3 percent annually. I would say there is seasonality in total accidents as the coefficient estimates in the summer in general not significantly higher than January (with the exception of August), while the coefficients in October, November, and December are significantly higher than January at the 99 percent level. Running an F-test for joint significance of the monthly dummies, we can reject the absence of seasonality at the 1 percent level with an F-stat of 5.15.

(iii) (5 pts) Adding wkends, unem, spdlaw, and beltlaw to the regression in part ii, we get a coefficient of -.0212 on unemployment. The inter- pretation is that unemployment lowers total accidents by 2.12 percent. The sign and magnitude seem to make sense if you think that many accidents occur during commutes.

(iv) (5 pts) The coefficient on speed law is -.0538, meaning that introducing the speed limit increase to 65 mph actually reduced traffic accidents by 5.38 percent. The coefficient on beltlaw is .0954, meaning that man- dating seat belts actually increased accidents by 9.54 percent. Neither of these coefficients are the sign that I would expect. However, it is plausible that raising the speed limit eased congestion on roads and therefore could reduce accidents. Moreover, it is also possible that by people compensated for feeling ”safer” due to seatbelt laws by driving more recklessly.

(v) (5 pts) Using summarize prcfat you can see that the mean is. percent. Yes, it seems plausible that a little less than 1 percent of accidents resulted in at least one fatality.

(vi) (5 pts) Running the regression from part iii with prcf at as the depen- dent variable, we get coefficients of .067 on spdlaw which is significant at the 1 percent level and -.029 on beltlaw which is not significant at the 20 percent level. The spdlaw result is intuitive since if people are allowed to drive faster, we expect more accidents to have fatalities. Since the beltlaw estimate is negative, we may think that seat belt laws reduced fatalities; however, it is not significantly different from zero.