Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Evaluating Market Efficiency in Bond and Stock Markets: A Look at the Evidence, Lecture notes of Economics

The concept of market efficiency in bond and stock markets, as presented in Fama's survey and various studies. The efficient-markets theory implies that no unexploited profit opportunities will exist in securities markets. the correlation between stock prices, long-term bond yields, and past information, as well as the implications for monetary transmission mechanisms. The data used in the analysis comes from Lawrence Fisher and James H. Lorie's 'A Half Century of Returns on Stocks and Bonds'. The document also addresses the presence of heteroscedasticity in bond and stock returns and the implications for market efficiency.

What you will learn

  • What is the correlation between stock prices, long-term bond yields, and past information?
  • How do monetary transmission mechanisms in structural macro models focus on long-term securities markets?
  • What is the efficient-markets theory and how does it apply to bond and stock markets?
  • What are the implications of the findings for the characterizations of bond and stock markets in macroeconomic models?

Typology: Lecture notes

2021/2022

Uploaded on 08/05/2022

nguyen_99
nguyen_99 🇻🇳

4.2

(80)

1K documents

1 / 46

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
FREDERIC S. MISHKIN
University of Chicago
Eicient-Markets
Theoryv
Implications
for
Monetary
Policy
EXPECTATIONS have come to the forefront in recent discussions
of
macroeconomic
policy. The theory
of rational
expectations, initially
de-
veloped by Muth, asserts that both firms and individuals,
as rational
agents,
have expectations that will not differ significantly
from optimal
forecasts made using all available
information. When rational
expecta-
tions are
imposed
on macroeconomic models, some
startling observations
emerge.
Lucas finds
that changes
in policy affect the parameters
of many
behavioral
relations;
thus
the use of current econometric
models to project
effects of macro policy can be misleading.'
Rational expectations,
to-
gether with the "natural rate hypothesis" of Friedman
and Phelps,
lend
support
to the proposition
that a deterministic
monetary policy has no
effect
on the output
of the economy.
In these models only unanticipated
Note: I thank
Andrew B. Abel, Dennis W. Carlton, Eugene F. Fama, Nicholas J.
Gonedes, Robert E. Lucas, Jr., Donald N. McClosky, Michael Mussa, A. R. Nobay,
Steven M. Sheffrin,
Robert J. Shiller, and members
of the Brookings panel for their
helpful comments. I also appreciate
the help of Lawrence Fisher, who offered data
on long-term government bonds as well as advice, and Stephen Grubaugh, who
provided
competent research
assistance.
This article benefited from comments made
at the Finance and Money Workshops
at the University of Chicago and the Money
Workshops at Harvard and Northwestern universities. The research has been sup-
ported in part by the Social Science Research Council.
1. Robert E. Lucas, Jr., "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique," in Karl
Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer, eds., The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, Carne-
gie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 1 (Amsterdam: North-
Holland, 1976), pp. 19-46.
0007430317810003-0707$00.2510
C Brookings
Institution
pf3
pf4
pf5
pf8
pf9
pfa
pfd
pfe
pff
pf12
pf13
pf14
pf15
pf16
pf17
pf18
pf19
pf1a
pf1b
pf1c
pf1d
pf1e
pf1f
pf20
pf21
pf22
pf23
pf24
pf25
pf26
pf27
pf28
pf29
pf2a
pf2b
pf2c
pf2d
pf2e

Partial preview of the text

Download Evaluating Market Efficiency in Bond and Stock Markets: A Look at the Evidence and more Lecture notes Economics in PDF only on Docsity!

FREDERIC S. MISHKIN

Universityof Chicago

Eicient-MarketsTheoryv

Implications for

Monetary Policy

EXPECTATIONShave come to the forefront in recent discussions of

macroeconomicpolicy. The theoryof rationalexpectations,initiallyde-

veloped by Muth,

asserts that both firms and individuals,as rational

agents, have expectationsthat will not differsignificantlyfrom

optimal

forecastsmade using all availableinformation.When rationalexpecta-

tions are imposedon macroeconomicmodels,some startlingobservations

emerge.Lucasfindsthat changesin policy affectthe parametersof many

behavioralrelations;thusthe use of currenteconometricmodelsto project

effects

of macro policy

can be misleading.'

Rational expectations,to-

getherwith the

"naturalrate hypothesis"of Friedmanand Phelps, lend

supportto the propositionthat a deterministicmonetarypolicy has no

effect on the outputof the economy.In these models only unanticipated

Note: I thank Andrew B. Abel, Dennis W. Carlton, Eugene F. Fama, Nicholas J.

Gonedes, Robert E. Lucas, Jr., Donald N. McClosky, Michael Mussa, A. R. Nobay,

Steven M. Sheffrin,Robert J. Shiller, and members of the Brookingspanel

for their

helpful comments. I also appreciate

the help

of Lawrence Fisher, who offered data

on long-term government bonds as well as advice, and Stephen Grubaugh, who

provided competent research assistance. This article benefited from comments made

at the Finance

and Money Workshops at the University of Chicago and the Money

Workshops at Harvard and Northwestern universities. The research has been sup-

ported in part by

the Social Science Research Council.

  1. Robert E. Lucas, Jr., "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique,"in Karl

Brunnerand Allan H. Meltzer, eds., The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, Carne-

gie-Rochester Conference Series

on Public Policy, vol.

1 (Amsterdam: North-

Holland, 1976), pp. 19-46.

0007430317810003-0707$00.2510C BrookingsInstitution

708 BrookingsPaperson EconomicActivity,3:

monetarypolicy affectsoutput, and there is some empiricalsupportfor

this proposition.

Several major objectionshave been raised against

rational expecta-

tions theory. The cost of obtainingand analyzinginformationmay be

quite high for many agents in the economy, and their use of rules of

thumbto formexpectationsin decisionmakingmightwell be appropriate,

even thoughthese expectationswould not be quite "rational."3In addi-

tion, the implicationsof certainrational-expectationsmodels-in particu-

lar, the so-called equilibriummodels of the businesscycle that include

both the naturalrate hypothesisand rational expectations-have been

criticizedas beinghighlyunrealistic.It has been arguedthatthesemodels

cannot explainthe persistenceof unemployment,and they are therefore

an inaccurate guide to the effects of policy.

Although

the existenceof rationalexpectationsin all marketsin the

economycanbe questioned,it seemssensiblethatbehaviorin speculative-

auctionmarkets,such as those in which bonds and commonstocks

are

traded,would reflectavailableinformation.As is discussedbelow, plau-

sible and less stringentconditionsare needed to demonstratethat, as a

useful approximationfor macroeconomicanalysis,bond and stock mar-

kets areefficient-that is, pricesin thesemarketsfully reflectavailablein-

formation.

When this concept is tested on bond and stock markets,as

Fama's survey

in support

of the efficient-marketstheory states, "con-

tradictoryevidenceis sparse."

Efficient-marketstheory has major implicationsfor the econometric

evaluationof policy

as well as for macro forecastingmethodology.6In-

  1. See Thomas J. Sargent and Neil Wallace, "'Rational' Expectations,the Opti-

mal

Monetary Instrument,and the Optimal Money Supply Rule," Journal of Politi-

cal Economy, vol. 83 (April 1975), pp. 241-54,

and Robert J. Barro,

"Unanticipated

Money

Growth and Unemployment in the United States,"American Economic Re-

view, vol. 67 (March 1977), pp. 101-15.

  1. See William Poole, "Rational Expectations in the Macro Model,"

BPEA,

2: 1976, pp.

463-505, and Robert J. Shiller, "RationalExpectationsand the Dynamic

Structure

of Macroeconomic Models: A Critical Review," Journal of

Monetary

Economics, vol. 4 (January 1978), pp.

1-44.

  1. Franco Modigliani, "The Monetarist Controversy or, Should We Forsake

Stabilization Policies?" American Economic Review, vol.

67 (March 1977), pp.

1-19.

  1. Eugene F. Fama, "EfficientCapital Markets:

A Review of Theory and Em-

pirical Work,"Journalof Finance, vol. 25 (May

1970), p. 417.

Poole

discussed some of these implications in his "Rational Expectations in

the Macro Model"; this paper extends some of Poole's analysis.

710 BrookingsPaperson Economic Activity,

3:

libriumexpected return

(or "normal"return), R*, is viewed as deter-

minedby factorslike risk

and the covarianceof Rt

with the overal mar-

ket return,the abovepropositioncan be statedin a slightlydifferent

way.

Efficient-marketstheory

impliesthat no unexploitedprofitopportunities

will exist in securitiesmarkets:at today'sprice,

market participants

can-

not expectto earna higherthannormalreturnby investing

in thatsecurity.

One important

attributeof the theory embodiedin 2 is that not all

participantsin the securities

marketshave to use informationefficiently.

Some marketparticipantscould even

be irrationalwithoutinvalidating

marketefficiency.

Equation

2 is analogousto an arbitragecondition.Arbitrageurs

who

arewilling

to speculatemayperceiveunexploitedprofitopportunities

and

purchaseor sell

securitiesuntil the price is drivento the point where

holds approximately.9Several

costs involvedin speculatingcould drivea

wedgebetweenthe left- and right-handsides of

Because

the collection

of information

is not costless, arbitrageurswould have to be compen-

satedfor thatcost and

othersincurredin theiractivities,as well as for the

risk they bear. Transactionand storage costs

would also affect 2. Yet

securities

have the key featureof homogeneity,for they are merelypaper

claims to income

on real assets. Transactionsand holding costs should

thus be negligible,while compensation

of arbitrageursand the cost of

informationcollection (especially

for the data on interestrates analyzed

here)

shouldbe quitesmallrelativeto the total valueof securities

traded.

Therefore,

the efficient-marketstheory of 2 is a close approximation

to

realityand could

be extremelyusefulin macroeconomicanalysis.

  1. An example

can be found in the capital-asset-pricingmodel of Sharpe

and

Lintner

discussedin Fama, "EfficientCapital Markets."

  1. Depending on the arbitrage condition,

2 may not always hold exactly. In-

deed, as Sanford

J. Grossman and Joseph E. Stiglitz have pointed out,

if 2 held

exactly, efficient-marketstheory would imply

a paradox.

See "Information and

Competitive

Price Systems,"American Economic Review, vol. 66 (May

1976), pp.

246-53. If all information were fully

reflected in a market according to 2, obtaining

information would have zero return. Thus the market

would not be able to reflect

this information

because it would be uncollected and hence unknown. The Gross-

man and Stiglitz argument does not, however,

deny the usefulness of efficient-

markets

theory for macroeconomic analysis. Even though their argument

implies

that information collection

must be compensated, the difference between the right-

and

left-hand sides of 2 would be negligible if the cost of collecting

a piece

of infor-

mation were small,

as it is for the data on interest rates discussed in this article.

FredericS. Mishkin 711

MARTINGALE IMPLICATIONS

Whetherthere are significant

correlationsbetween past information

andcurrentchangesin securitiespricesis the crucialissuein the empirical

tests and analysisof this article.The martingalemodel,whichis a special

case

of efficient-markets theory,

leads to hypotheses

about these corre-

lations.

Equation 2 impliesthat, if the excess return,R- R", is regressedon

any past availableinformation, 5t-l,

the coefficientson this past informa-

tion should be zero. A commonassumptionin tests of marketefficiency

is thatthe equilibriumreturn,R*,

is constantover time.

This thenimplies

that thereis no correlationbetweenthe actualretur, Rt,

andpast infor-

mation,

#t-,

If

0t-l

is takento be past returnson the security-that is,

0t-l

=

Rt-,

or Rt2,

and so

on-no serial correlation

of one-periodreturnsshouldbe

found. This

is the basic martingaleresult.

On the other hand, if

cP-,

in-

cludes variablesthat describeother informationthat was publiclyavail-

able in the past (or linearcombinationsof them), the generalresultis that

returnsare uncorrelatedwiththese variables,even thoughthey aregener-

ated outsidethe marketfor the security

in question.

In Fama'sterminol-

ogy,

tests of the serial correlationof returnsare "weakform" tests;tests

of the more generalproposition

are "semi-strongform"tests.

An examplemightclarifythe intuitionbehindthesemartingaleresults.

Assumethat the returnfor a securityover the comingperiodis positively

correlatedwith the volume of tradingin that securityat the beginningof

the period. Then if the tradingvolume were high today, a returnthat is

higherthan normalfor this securitywould be expected over the subse-

quentperiod.This implies a contradictionbecausean unexploitedprofit

opportunitywould now exist. Efficient-marketstheory indicatesthat in

this case the security

would have been immediately

bid up

in price until

the expected

returnwas equal

to the normal return,

and the positivecor-

relation between past trading

volume and the return from this security

would have disappeared.

One crucialpoint is centralto an understanding

of much of the

em-

pirical literatureon efficientmarkets.Even if the equilibriumreturn,

R*, is not constantover time, so long as its variationis small relativeto

other sourcesof variationsin returns,the correlationof Rt

and t

will

FredericS. Mishkin 713

modem, structuralmacroeconometricmodels view

monetarypolicy as

affectingaggregatedemand primarilythroughits effects on long-term

bond and stock markets. Incorporatingthe implicationsof efficient-

marketstheory into these models is thus crucialto an understandingof

monetarypolicy

and the formulationof appropriateprescriptionsfor

stabilizationpolicy.

Efficient-MarketsTheoryandtheTermStructureof InterestRates

Monetarytransmissionmechanismsfound in the literature,especially

those of structuralmacroeconometricmodels, focus primarilyon the

effects of monetary policy that operate through long-term securities

markets.

Most traditionalmechanismsin structuralmacro models emphasize

the effects of monetarypolicy on long-terminterest rates and on the

cost of capital.Changesin the latteralterspendingfor both businessand

consumerinvestment.Variantsof the cost-of-capitalapproachalso stress

the effects of the stock market on investment,either directly through

changesin the cost of capital,or throughthe ratio of the value of capital

to its replacementcost, the Tobin-Brainardq ratio. The stock marketis

also cited as a factor in consumerexpendituresthroughits effects on

wealth and the compositionof the householdbalancesheet.

The effect of credit availabilityon residentialhousingis the one sig-

nificant monetary transmissionmechanismthat does

not operate pri-

marily throughlong-termsecuritiesmarkets.Savingflows into and out

of institutionsissuingmortgagesare viewedas importantdeterminantsof

the residentialhousingcycle. Recentwork,however,findsthatthe effects

of creditavailabilityare

not as clear-cutas was previouslythought,espe-

  1. A more extensive survey of the literatureon monetary transmissionappears

in Frederic S. Mishkin, "EfficientMarkets Theory: Its Implications for Monetary

Policy," report 7809 (University of Chicago, Center for Mathematical Studies in

Business and Economics, February 1978). References to research on the monetary

transmissionmechanisms discussed here can be found in this working paper. Other

recent surveys are W. C. Brainardand R. N. Cooper, "EmpiricalMonetary Macro-

economics: What Have We Learned in the Last 25 Years?" American Economic

Review, vol. 65 (May 1975), pp. 167-75, and Franco Modigliani, "The Channels of

Monetary Policy

in the Federal Reserve-MIT-Universityof Pennsylvania Econo-

metric Model of the United States," in G. A. Renton, ed., Modelling the Economy

(Heinemann Educational Books for the Social Science Research Council, 1975),

pp. 240-67.

714 BrookingsPaperson Economic

Activity,3:

cially for single-familyhousing.In any case, the literatureon monetary

transmissionindicatesthatbehaviorin long-termbond andstockmarkets

is criticalto the

propertiesof macroeconomicmodels. The implications

of efficient-marketstheoryfor behaviorin these marketsshould thus be

examinedcarefully.

The link betweenmonetarypolicy andlong-termbond ratesand stock

prices in structuralmacroeconometricmodels can be characterizedas

follows. An actionby the FederalReserve,such

as a changein the dis-

count rate or unborrowedreserves,leads to a change in short-termin-

terest rates, usually throughsome kind of money-demandrelationship.

Changes

in short-term rates

are then linkedto long-termratesthrougha

term-structureequationin which the long-termrate respondsto a long

distributedlag on currentand past short-termrates.14In models with a

stockmarketsector (such as the MPSmodel), long-termratesthenaffect

the value of stocks

with a distributed lag.

The previous discussionof efficient-marketstheory leads to doubts

about the appropriatenessof these term-structureequations.First, it is

disturbingthat these equationsallow the predictionof changesin long-

term rates and stock prices from publicly availableinformationin the

past (in particular,interestrates). Second,the use of these equationsin

the contextof policy

evaluationis suspicious

because expectations

about

changesin policy have no role

in these equations.

I

now turn to a more

detaileddiscussionof the problemsthat arisein theseequations.

THE TERM-STRUCTURE EQUATION

The typicalequationlinkingshort-andlong-termratesis derivedfrom

the expectationshypothesis

of the termstructure.Let RL7 be the yield to

maturity

of an n-period

discountbond at time t,

and let rt be the one-

period short-term

rate at time t. Assume that there is a positive

but

constant liquidity premiumequal

to k. Using

the approximation

that

ln(1 + rt)

= rt, the expectationshypothesiscanbe characterizedby

RLt

k

(-n)

Et(rt

  • rt+l+

rt+,-),

  1. This is modeled either with the long-term rate regressed directly on current

and past

short-termrates or with a Koyck-typelag

mechanismin which the long-term

rate is regressed

on the current short-termrate and the long-term rate is lagged one

period.

716 BrookingsPaperson EconomicActivity,3:

and becausert+2 = rt+

ut+2 -XUl

(8) Et(rt+2) Et(rt+,)

t

More

generally,

(9) Ej(r1+j)

=

Et(rt+i)

-1- , rs

for i = 1, 2, 3, 4,.

Substituting

9 into equation

yields

(10) RL

=

k+ Irt+ (n-i) (?Lr)l

nr

n- I- X\

= k+ -t+

n

(? r'

n nl \I-A

or, equivalently,

n

+rt

+n -ic

(I 1)

RLt = k + n

E

X.irt,;.

n n

i_

A compelling

reason for the additionof an errortermis that market

participantshave informationon othervariablesbesides

currentand past

short-termrates. Thus, based on this information,their expectationof

futureu may not be

zero. The long-term

bond rate,RL', will reflectthese

expectationsand will fluctuatearoundthe

values given by 11 as

new in-

formationon these variablesis receivedby the market.In addition,an

errorterm, et,

should be added to 11 to alow for possible

shifts in the

liquiditypremium.17Thus

rt n-i

RL

n

ir,_. + et

n

n

Equation12,

whichuses a distributed lag

on currentandpast variables

to reflectexpectations,

can be used in empirical

workto provide

valuable

information.

For example,

estimatesof equations

like 12 strongly

indi-

cate that movements

in long-term

rates are heavily

influenced by

move-

ments in

short-termrates. However,

even though

these term-structure

equations

are useful as a summary

of average

historical experience

dur-

  1. This discussion does not imply

that eg is serially

uncorrelated.It is entirely

conceivable

that information on other variables relevant to expectationsof future u

is serially

correlated.Thus etmight

also be serially

correlated.

FredericS. Mishkin 717

ing the sample period, they can be viewed as structuralequationsonly

underextremely

restrictiveand highlyimplausibleassumptions.In terms

of the equationsystemabove,Xwouldhave to be an unvarying

structural

parameterbecausethe distributedlag coefficientsof rt will

be alteredby

any changein X, which reflectsthe time-seriesprocess of the short-term

rate.For example,

with a largerX,the shockto the short-termrateis less

persistentover time and the distributedlag

weighton the currentshort-

termrate is smaller,while the lag weights

on short-termrates furtherin

the past would be correspondinglyhigher.If X is close

to zero,

the time-

series processbecomessimilarto a randomwalk, and the weighton

the

currentshort-termrate approachesone, while past short-termrateshave

little

importance.In effect,X can be unvaryingonly if marketparticipants

assignedto every surprise

in short-termrates the same degree of per-

sistence (or samerate of decay) in the future,regardless

of any informa-

tion they had aboutthe sourceand significanceof the disturbance.

Realistically,changesin expectationsof policy ruleswould alterX and

hence the distributedlag weights

of 12. For example,if FederalReserve

policy were expectedto resultin a permanentloweringof

the short-term

rate by 100 basispoints, equation 3 would not predicta slow adjustment

while 12 could do so."

In policy

evaluation or forecasting, the estimated distributedlag

weightsof term-structure

equationsare assumedto be constantregardless

of whatpolicy changeis being evaluated

or anticipated.

Yet, as shouldbe

clearfromthe aboveexample,the invarianceof

the weights

is a dangerous

assumption.

The example

also can be used to clarifyinterpretationsof the impor-

tant work on the term structureby Modiglianiand Shiller.

They indi-

cate that,if expectationsare"rational,"an estimatedterm-structureequa-

tion should have coefficientsthat are consistent with the time-series

behaviorof variablessuch as short-termrates. This is equivalent,in the

above example,

to findingthat the X estimatedin 12 is no differentfrom

the Xof 5.

Their finding

that this conditionis met andthatthe termstruc-

tureis rational

does not imply,however,

that such a term-structureequa-

tion is invariantto policychanges

and can

be used as a structuralequation

  1. The point raised here is similar to that made by Lucas in his consumption

example describedin "EconometricPolicy Evaluation."

  1. Modigliani and Shiller, "Inflation, Rational Expectations, and the Term

Structureof Interest

Rates."

FredericS. Mishkin 719

would be a normal returnfor a security

with the risk characteristics of

long-termbonds-that is, there should be no unexploitedprofitoppor-

tunities.Givenreasonable measuresof Et(r

+1), it is unlikelythatthis effi-

cient-marketsconstraintwould be satisfiedbecause forecasts using an

equationsuch as 4 do not use all availablerelevantinformation.In gen-

eratingforecasts,the marketwill use informationfromdistributed lags of

past variables,and it will also be concernedwith subjectiveinformation,

such as whetheror not the mood in Congressis to pursueexpansionary

fiscal policy. As was discussed above, the existence of error terms in

equationssuch as 4 and 12 implies that past informationbesides short-

term rates is importantto expectationsof futureshort-termrates. Thus

when 4 is used to forecast RL" , it does not exploit informationem-

bodied in RLt, whichin an efficientmarketreflectsall availableinforma-

tion. The resultingforecastof RL7+1is less than optimalwhen compared

with RL' and will probablyimply the existenceof an unexploitedprofit

opportunity.

To ascertainhow seriousa violationof marketefficiencyis impliedby

one-periodforecasts with equationssuch as 4, a numberof experiments

have been conductedthat are akin to simulationexperiments.These are

not intendedto settle the issue of whetherfinancialmarketsare efficient,

but ratherto illustratethe propertiesof term-structureequationslike 4.

Using term-structureequations estimatedover several sample periods,

along with several measuresof Et

(rt+i), the implied,expectedquarterly

returnswere calculatedfor the mostrecentfive-yearperiodfor whichdata

are available.In the interestof conservingspace, only one experimentis

discussed below. (Other experimentsare discussedin note 32.) The re-

sults discussedin the text are by no means atypical,and, if anything,of

the results I explored,these tend to be among the least unfavorableto

term-structureequationsof the formof 4.

Modiglianiand Sutch23 have estimateda term-structure equation in

which the long-termgovernmentbond rate is a seventeen-quarterdis-

tributedlag on currentand past 90-day treasurybill rates,with the coeffi-

cients of past bill rates lying on a fourth-orderpolynomialwith an end-

point constraint.In the example discussedhere, this equationhas been

  1. In a similar way, simulation experiments with macroeconometric models

only illustrate the propertiesof these models and do not settle the question of what

the true structureof the economy is.

  1. Modigliani and Sutch, "Innovations"and "Debt Management."

720 BrookingsPaperson Economic Activity,3:

reestimatedover the 1964-76 period,24using the same polynomiallag

constraintsas Modiglianiand Sutchand a correctionfor first-orderserial

correlation.The governmentbond seriesuses yields fromtaxablegovern-

ment bonds callablein ten yearsor more,with bondschosenso that tax-

induceddistortionsfromcapitalgainsandestateprivilegesareminimized.

Both the bondyieldsandthetreasurybillratesareend-of-quarterfigures.

The reestimatedterm-structureequationusing ordinaryleast squares

is as follows, with the coefficienton

aut-

equal to the first-order serial

correlationcoefficient;standard errorsare in parenthesesas is the case

throughoutthe article.All interestrate variablesare expressedin frac-

tions-that is, a 6 percentyieldis 0.06.

(15) RGOVt

RTBt

16

  • ,biRTBt_i+ 0.5212ft-, +

Et

16

b = 0.9444,

R2 = 0.9450; Durbin-Watson= 2.12; standarderror = 0.0033;

where

RGOVt

= long-termgovernmentbond yield,end of quarter

RTBt

= treasurybill rate at end of quarter.

At first glance,

the term-structure equationlooks quite satisfactory.

The fit is good-the percentageof varianceexplainedis high and the

  1. The 1964-76 sample period has been used for all my empirical tests because

the need for forward rates in some of the empirical work requires that the sample

period begin no earlier than 1964. Whenever possible, I also conducted empirical

tests on the longer sample period from 1954-76. (Some of the results from the

longer sample period are reportedin the notes.)

  1. Lawrence Fisher supplied me with these bond data, which also include the

returns from holding these bonds. The data are described in Lawrence Fisher and

James H. Lorie, A Half Century of Returns on Stocks and Bonds: Rates of Return

on Investmentsin Common Stock and on U.S. TreasurySecurities,1926-1976 (Uni-

versity of Chicago, GraduateSchool of Business, 1977). The Board of Governorsof

the Federal Reserve System supplied me with the data

on prime commercial paper

and the 90-day treasurybill market yield for the last tradingday of the quarteron a

discount basis.

722 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,3:

tationsfrom realizationsshouldbe seriallyuncorrelated.If this were not

the case, the expectationsmeasurecould clearlybe made more accurate

by using this informationon serial correlation,and this measurecould

not representexpectationsin an efficientmarket.Box and Pierce have

suggesteda so-calledQ statisticto test for serialcorrelation.28They find

that,for anunfilteredseries,

K

Q(K

=

T E rk,

k-I

where

T

= number of observations

Pk

= correlationbetweenthe seriesand its value

k

periods

earlier.

This Q(K)is distributed approximatelyas X2(K)underthe hypothesisHo

that

rl P2 =*** Pk-=.

For RTBt

  • ERFt

over the 1964-76 period, Q(12) = 8.7 and Q(24)

= 22.0, while the critical Q

at 5 percentare 21.

and 36.4, respectively.

Thus the hypothesisthat the firsttwelve or twenty-fourautocorrelations

are zero cannot be rejected,and the forward-ratemeasurefor expecta-

tions meetsthe criterionimpliedby marketefficiency.

An alternativemeasureof expectationscan be obtainedfromthe time-

series process of the treasury

bill rate. Using

Box-Jenkinsidentification

procedures,an autoregressivemodel was estimatedover the 1964-

period29as

(19) RTBt

= 0.0096 + 0. RTBt&

RTBt,

RTBt..

  • Ut.

Durbin-Watson

= 1.82.

  1. G. E. P. Box and David

A. Pierce, "Distribution

of Residual Autocorrela-

tions in Autoregressive-Integrated

Moving Average Time Series Models," Journal

of the American Statistical Association, vol. 65 (December 1970), pp. 1509-26.

The

Q-statisticsbelow were derived using Charles R. Nelson's ESTIMATE program.

  1. Significantheteroscedasticitywas present in the regression,so it is estimated

here with weighted least squares, using a proceduresimilar to that outlined below.

FredericS. Mishkin 723

Takingexpectationsof both sides of 19 yields an autoregressivemea-

sureof

E,(RTB

+,), whichis

ERARt+i

0.0096 + 0.7859 RTBt

RTBt&2-

RTBt4.

The Q(12) statisticfor

RTB,

  • ERARt

is distributedas X2(9). For the

1964-76 periodit is 6.7, while the criticalQ at the 5 percentlevel is 16.9.

Furthermore,Q(24) = 10.7, whilethe criticalQ at 5 percentequals32.7.

Thus thereis no evidenceof serialcorrelationin the forecasterrors.

Based on 16 and either of the two measuresof E

(RTB,+,),

implied

one-periodquarterlyreturnsfrom holdinga long-termgovernmentbond

have been calculatedfor the 1972-76 period.Because these government

bonds are not consols, a formula more complicatedthan 14 generates

these returns,usinginformationon the maturitydate of each bond.

The implied expected returnsfrom 15, the term-structureequation

(shown

in table 1), illustratehow forecastsfromthis type of equationare

inconsistentwith marketefficiency.3'The impliedexpectedreturnsfluc-

tuate substantiallyand the violationof efficientmarketsis severebecause

it is quite implausiblethat normal returnsfor long-termbonds would

equal the implied returnsof table 1. Using either measureof expected

RTB, the quarterlyreturnson governmentbonds were 20 percent or

higherat an annualrate at the end of 1976, well above what can be con-

sidereda normalrate of returnfor this type of security.Expectedlosses

in nominaltermsappearfor somequartersof 1973 and 1974, but nominal

  1. The measure of autoregressive expectations suffers from the same problem

that arises for term-structureequations such as 4: the coefficients in the equation

are not invariant to a change in policy regime. The time-seriesprocess of the short-

term rate thus might change over time, and ERARt

might at times be a poor measure

of expectations. ERARt

also suffers from the disadvantage that it restricts itself to

information on past short-term rates, while the market may use other information

in generating its expectations.However, ERARt

is used in the above experimentbe-

cause it also shows that implied expected returnsfrom equation 15 are inconsistent

with market efficiency according to a number of expectations measures.

  1. Because of the way bond-pricing conventions reflect bond coupon payment,

there are some subtle technical issues in calculating bond returns that have been

allowed for in Fisher's data on bond returnsand in the calculations found here. The

Fisher series uses the average of

bid and asked prices in calculating returns, and

transactionscosts are not included in his calculations of quarterlybond returns.

Frederic S. Mishkin 725

returnscould never be negativewith the existenceof money,

a risk-free

assetwith a nonnegative return.

In summary,a typical term-structureequationis theoreticallyan in-

adequatestructuralequationin a macro model. More direct empirical

tests follow, which indicate that past information,

such as that used in

term-structure equations,is not particularlyhelpfulin predictingchanges

in long-term ratesor stock prices.This providesfurtherevidencethat the

use of theseterm-structureequationsshouldbe abandoned.

Testsof Efficient-MarketsTheoryfor BondandStockMarkets

The tests of marketefficiencyconductedin this section use quarterly

returnsfor the long-termgovernmentbonds discussed above and the

quarterly,value-weightedstock returnsof New York Stock Exchange

stocks compiled by the Universityof Chicago, Centerfor Researchin

SecurityPrices.33These returnsareexpressedin fractions.Otherinforma-

tion includes data on treasurybills and forwardrates discussedabove

and on the Moody'sAaa corporatebond rate.Because misleadingresults

can be obtainedfrom tests

with averageddata, all informationon security

  1. Using the same estimation proceduresas in 15, implied quarterlyreturnsfor

1972-76 analogous to those in table 1 are as follows:

Period of Serial

Equation estimation correlation Range (percent)

1 1964-76 Uncorrected -10.6 to 29.

2 1954-76 Corrected -3.6 to 23.

3 1954-76 Uncorrected -6. to 34.

4 1964-71 Corrected -51.4 to 178.

5 1954-71 Corrected -3.3 to 35.

The sum of the coefficientson the treasury

bill rates in these equations ranges from

0.99 to 1.31. All the term-structureequations discussedin this note are characterized

by

the same difficultiesas equation 15.

In the 1964-76 sample period, a change of

11 basis points in the long-term gov-

ernment bond rate correspondsto a 4 percentage point movement in the quarterly

bond return at an annual rate. Thus if the equilibriumreturnfor these bonds is taken

to be close to the return on 90-day bills, table 1 indicates that the long-term bond

rate predicted by 15 never differed from the efficient-marketsprediction for bond

yields by

more than 60 basis points.

Quarterly

stock returns have been computed for these data from the value-

weighted,monthly returns, with dividendsreinvested.

726 BrookingsPaperson EconomicActivity,3:

pricesis takenat a particularpoint in time." The bond and stock returns

are calculatedfrom securityprices at the beginningand the end of the

quarter.All tests are carriedout on the 1964-76 sampleperiod. (Addi-

tionaltestson longersampleperiods,whenthiswaspossible,arediscussed

in the notes.)

Particularattentionmustbe paid to possibleheteroscedasticityin these

tests.Heteroscedasticitydoes not lead to inconsistentparameterestimates,

but it does lead to inconsistenttest statistics.Because the test statistics

are of primaryinterest in the empiricalwork below, correctionsfor

heteroscedasticityaremadeif necessary.

Two types of efficient-markettests are conducted.Weak-formtests

analyzewhetherone-periodlong-termbond or stock returnsare serially

uncorrelated-the implicationof the martingalemodelof the firstsection.

Both the Q(K) statistic,whichjointlytestswhetherthe firstK autocorre-

lationsarezero, andtest statisticson individualautocorrelationsareused.

For semistrongform tests, the efficient-marketsmodel can be charac-

terizedby the followinglinearequation:

(21) Rs

R* +

#(Xt-Xt) + et,

where

e

= expected values conditional on all past publicly available

information

Rt = one-periodreturnon a securityfor the periodt - I to t

R*= equilibrium return

Xt

= a variable(or vectorof variables)relevant

to the pricingof the

security

for the period

t - 1 to t

= coefficient(or vectorof coefficients)

= white-noiseerror process.

The returnsin this equationdeviatefromthe equilibriumreturn only

when

newinformationis receivedby the market-that is, whenthereis a surprise,

Xt- X 0. Marketefficiencyimplies,therefore,that in a regression

equationof the form

N

(22) Rt= Rt

+ 3(X. -

Xe)

ED7$(Xg,

  • Xt_)
  • Eg,

i-i

For example, security prices averaged over a quarterwill not follow a ran-

dom walk even though the price series can be characterizedas a random walk. See

Holbrook Working, "Note on the Correlationof First Differences of Averages in a

Random Chain,"Econometrica, vol. 28 (October 1960), pp. 916-18.