



















Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Prepare for your exams
Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points to download
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Community
Ask the community for help and clear up your study doubts
Discover the best universities in your country according to Docsity users
Free resources
Download our free guides on studying techniques, anxiety management strategies, and thesis advice from Docsity tutors
Intergroup conflict from micro, meso, and macro structural levels, discussing how Realistic Group Conflict Theory (RGCT) and Resource Dependence Theory (RDT) approach the impetus for conflict. The paper proposes Resource Uncertainty Conflict Theory (RUCT) as a synthesis of the two views. RGCT is a micro and meso-theoretical explanation for intergroup conflict, focusing on contrasting interests and incompatible goals. RUCT integrates RGCT with RDT, linking resource uncertainty with competition and collaboration. The document also discusses the conditions under which group interaction leads to competitive or collaborative behavior and the intensity of conflict experienced by groups.
Typology: Exams
1 / 27
This page cannot be seen from the preview
Don't miss anything!
A Resource Dependence Perspective on Inter-Group Conflict: The Synthesis of Two Theories Conflict has been a fundamental part of human interaction since the beginning of history. It can be as benign as a sibling rivalry or as malignant as a world war. It may involve two people or two billion people and its duration is equally unfixed. Although the manifestations of conflict vary across time and space, it remains an ever-present facet of our lives. In the fiercely competitive organizational landscape of the 21 st^ century, where economic winners and losers are commensurately rewarded or punished in an increasingly short time span, conflict among companies, departments, teams, and individuals is ubiquitous and intense. However, in order for businesses to function and turn a profit in today’s global economy, both inter-group and inter- organizational cooperation and collaboration are increasingly necessary. Therefore, from an organizational behavioral perspective, understanding the origins of conflict, and how it transpires within and between organizations, is crucial.
We draw from the organizational theory literature to define conflict herein as a two- pronged interaction that begins with a difference of opinion and subsequently leads to a corresponding behavioral response from one of the involved parties. In our view, a disagreement that is wholly internalized and does not lead to pushback is the mere failure of two minds to meet, and lacks the behavioral element commonly associated with conflict. Our definition is supported by existing literature associating conflict with a “breakdown” (March & Simon, 1958) and an “episodic, outcome-oriented struggle” (Dahrendorf, 1959) that is “marked by efforts at hindering, compelling, or injuring and by resistance or retaliation” (Katz & Kahn, 1978). However, our definition is not inconsistent with the transformative view of conflict management
(Folger & Bush, 1996), as the pushback in response to a disagreement may conceivably be constructive or healing in nature, leading to a win-win outcome for both groups.
Within organizational studies, the micro, meso, and macro domains all address the ever- present conflict phenomenon, yet they do so in different ways. For instance, the micro and meso approaches usually focus on behavioral aspects of individuals (O’Neill et al., 2013; De Wit et al., 2012), personality factors (Bradley et al., 2015), characteristics of group composition (Bendersky & Hays, 2012, Fehr & Gelfand, 2015; Okimoto, Wenzel, & Hornsey, 2015) and aspects of the type and source of the conflict itself (Weingart, et al., 2015; Bradley et al., 2015). On the other hand, macro theories tend to explain the reason for tension, competition, and conflict between organizations in terms of the availability of resources (Hillman & Dalziel, 2003; Hillman, Cannella, & Paetzold, 2000), power asymmetry (Pache & Santos, 2013; Purdy & Gray, 2009; Santos & Eisenhardt, 2009), uncertainty (Davis & Cobb, 2009), and factors within the external environment such as group dynamics and competitive pressure (Boyd, 1990; Anthony et al, 2005); Scott & Davis, 2007). Despite their differing levels of analysis and terminology, however, we argue that the micro, meso, and macro perspectives have substantial conceptual overlap. Thus, we propose that they actually complement one another, and taken together, are likely to provide a more complete understanding of intergroup conflict than any one perspective does separately.
Specifically, in this paper, we address the topic of intergroup conflict from the micro, meso, and macro structural levels and discuss how two organizational theories approach the impetus for conflict from different perspectives, yet can be synthesized to form a more complete model. Our framework adopts an ecological approach (Bronfenbrenner, 1979) toward understanding social conflict, as other conflict scholars from the developmental psychology,
group conflict. Lastly, we offer propositions based on our proposed Resource Uncertainly Conflict Model (RUCM) and discuss implications for both research and practice.
Realistic Group Conflict Theory Realistic Group Conflict Theory (Sherif et al, 1961) is a foundational conflict theory that addresses the phenomenon from the micro and meso domains. This framework seeks to understand the functional relations between social groups (Sherif, 1966) from a social psychological perspective. Specifically, Sherif (1961) posited that intergroup hostility stems from competition motivated by rewards, which are extrinsic to the group. The theory predicts that opposing group interests in obtaining scarce resources promotes competition, whereas interdependent and supraordinate goals facilitates cooperation. Realistic Group Conflict Theory explains how contrasting interests can lead to behavioral responses characteristic of conflict in the context of intergroup competition. Interestingly, Sherif (1961) observed that intergroup antagonism not only sprang from competition over scarce resources, but also increased the identification and attachment among in-group members toward each other.
At its origins, RGCT represented a counter-culture push away from social exchange theories, which were popular at the time. Critics of widely-accepted ‘exchange perspective’ believed they oversimplified group interaction and relied too heavily on theories of animal behavior to explain interpersonal interaction. Alternatively, RGCT built on extant theories of intergroup behavior that were focused primarily on interpersonal, intragroup, or intrapsychic explanations of conflict (Sherif & Sherif, 1953; Sherif, Harvey, White, Hood & Sherif, 1961; Sherif, 1966). At the time it was conceptualized, RGCT was proposed as an alternative to Authoritarian Personality Theory (Adorno, Frenkel-Brunswik, Levinson, & Sanford, 1950), the Frustration-Aggression Framework (Dollard, Doob, Miller, Mowrer, & Sears, 1939), and the
Contact Hypothesis (Allport, 1954), all of which focused on intrapersonal psychic processes. Thus, Realistic Group Conflict Theory was one of the first social psychological theories of conflict that was not based purely on micro-theoretical explanations.
Add one more paragraph here… (Kim) Sherif’s Robbers Cave Experiment (1961) illustrates how RGCT incorporates both intrapersonal and interpersonal perspectives to better understand conflict. It showed that people have a deep need to maintain esteem through identification with their in-group, and that individuals can easily be made to create in-group/out-group categories based on arbitrary distinctions. It also revealed that competitive intergroup activities generate hostility toward out- group members despite the triviality of their group affiliations, while at the same time, facilitating the attachment of in-group members. Interestingly, the body of work found that an environment of competition could be transformed into collaboration with the introduction of supraordinate goals. Thus, RGCT introduced a more nuanced and multifaceted framework for understanding sources of conflict between groups which relied on more complex factors than those of basic interpersonal motivation (i.e. food, safety, sex, etc.) such as incompatible goals and competition over limited resources.
More recent applications of RGCT have extended these important findings to lay the foundation for domains such as organizational diversity and cross-cultural management (Brief, et al., 2005; Baumeister & Vohs, 2007; Esses, et al., 1998). Specifically, several theories within the domain of organizational diversity and cross-cultural management draw on aspects of RGCT to support the idea that opposing factions within and organization can be brought together using supraordinate goals and encouraging identification with in-group attributes and characteristics
which can generate new patterns of interdependence and power imbalances, also known as dependence asymmetry (Gulati & Sytch, 2007). Power or dependence asymmetry, defined as the extent to which one organization perceives that it is more powerful than a peer (Casciaro & Piskorski, 2005; Gulati & Sytch, 2009), impacts its strategy for managing exchange relationships, and influences its adoption of a collaborative versus competitive stance. Specifically, as the power imbalance increases, the weaker organization faces increasingly undesirable exchange conditions, leading to conflict (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978: 66-67).
Resource Dependency Theory is conceptualized at the organizational level of analysis, with firms posited to comprise “the fundamental units for understanding intercorporate relations and society” (Pfeffer, 1987: 26-27). Notwithstanding its explicit focus on large organizations, the foundation of RDT emerged in part from micro and meso-level conceptualizations (Hillman, Withers, & Collins, 2009) such as Emerson’s (1962) theory of power relations. Emerson proposed that social power was not a static phenomenon, but was instead a ratio derived from “ties of mutual dependence” capable of shifting over time. His theory was posited to apply to relationships at the individual or group level. Emerson (1962) proposed that social power was inexplicably bound to implied mutual relationship dependencies (parent to child, home builder to mortgage lender, etc.). He suggested that the degree of power imbalance could change based on two factors analogized to supply and demand, “availability” and “motivational investment” (Emerson, 1962: 33). Emerson’s conceptualization of a dynamic, relationship-determinate power network and resource “availability” (supply) are paralleled in the subsequent macro-level RDT, which posits that organizations are “constrained by network interdependencies with other organizations” and take actions leading to “new patterns of dependence” (Pfeffer, 1987), similar to the dynamic nature of Emerson’s power relationships between individuals. RDT also posits
that an organization’s existence hinges on control over limited environmental resources, in parallel to Emerson’s emphasis on resource availability. The recognition that dependencies shift over time is also shared by the Emerson (1961) and RDT perspectives.
Emerson (1962) theorized that the cultivation or denial of “alternative sources” for a dependency were potential “balancing operations” for a relationship lacking parity. Such “balancing operations” include the withdrawal of interest, the development of additional network connections by the weaker party (e.g., a home builder locating new potential mortgage lenders to escape a monopoly situation), coalition building, and the conveyance of status to the stronger party at a low cost to the weaker party (Emerson, 1962). Emerson’s “balancing operations” at the individual level also have macro counterparts within Resource Dependency Theory. Specifically, Pffefer and Salancik (1978: 108-115) posited that organizations faced with a dependency situation elect to either accept the imposed restraint or else modify their environment by seeking out other sources, stockpiling, pursuing a diversification strategy, merging with another entity, joint venturing, or adopting a cooptation approach such as granting the outsider organization a board seat. The conceptual similarities between Emerson’s (1961) micro and meso-level theory and RDT’s macro-level theory offers plausible support for the integration of macro concepts into our proposed intergroup conflict theory, as it suggests that macro-level manifestations of conflict are rooted in micro and meso-level social interactions.
In further support of multi-level conflict theory integration, scholars in social psychology studying the dynamics of interdependencies (i.e. Thibaut & Kelley, 1959; Kelley & Thibaut,
Casciaro and Piskorski (2005) present empirical support for a reformulated RDT. Specifically, they find that mutual dependence is a key predictor of mergers, whereas power imbalance is an obstacle. This result is consistent with Pfeffer and Salancik’s (1978) general proposition that to reduce environmental uncertainty, organizations will strategically manage their interorganizational relations.
Toward A Unification of Two Perspectives
We believe the intergroup conflict literature would gain theoretical depth from an integration of the meso Realistic Group Conflict Theory and macro Resource Dependency Theory perspectives. Blending these theories would provide a more holistic perspective on the influences and underlying causes of intergroup conflict, thereby strengthening our understanding of the phenomenon. Our approach considers the micro-level conceptualizations (e.g., Emerson,
Realistic Group Conflict Theory (Sherif, 1961) and Resource Dependence Theory (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978) explain group and firm interactions using different frames of reference and levels of analysis. RGCT explains intergroup conflict as a result of in-group/out- group tensions, an outcome of prejudice and hostility by means of competitive behavior, and as a manner of demonstrating loyalty and affiliation for one’s in-group. RDT, on the other hand, explains how firms develop interdependencies as a result of their need for scarce environmental assets in an uncertain environment and how these interactions lead to power differentials, competition and coordination among firms. Despite the contrast in structural levels between these two theories, we propose that RDT can be synthesized with RGCT to better explain intra- firm conflict than either approach is capable of doing alone.
Although the two theories have different origins, and rely on different methods and levels of analysis, substantial overlap exists between them and they both speak to the same phenomena- namely, the precursors to inter-group conflict. For instance, both theories view intergroup competition as a result of a group’s attempt to maintain sufficient resources for survival. Further, RDT and RGCT both explain differences in power as the product of zero-sum relationships with mutually exclusive goals. For instance, the Robbers Cave Experiment (Sherif,
Under the RDT perspective, the sharing of resources by two firms is also understood to not be exclusive of cooperation; in other words, mutual dependency is not always a zero sum game. Pfeffer and Salancik (1978:41) found that “the dependence of one organization on
outside actor, and the more tightly and broadly it is controlled in the external environment, the greater the level of uncertainty in accessing it. The foregoing represents a nuanced approach to resource scarcity that may not be wholly applicable to individuals but is plausibly salient to groups as well as organizations.
Pfeffer and Salancik (1976: 42) viewed uncertainty as a conceptually distinct causal outcome of interdependency and conflict, but also acknowledged that uncertainty represents a fundamental problem arising from mutual dependence. We propose that uncertainty can plausibly be related back to encompass the primary structural dimensions of the environment identified in RDT – munificence, concentration, and interconnectedness – and are also expressed in the three aspects of the environment deemed critical for determining mutual dependence – resource importance, resource scarcity, and the availability of alternates. Under our integrative perspective, the foregoing three aspects of the environment (importance, scarcity, and availability of alternates) are recast as dimensions of resource uncertainly, which we propose as a critical antecedent to intergroup competition. In the next section, we explicitly outline the proposed model and explain how it expands our current understanding of group conflict.
A Model of Inter-Group Conflict Influenced by Resource Dependence
We propose that the understanding of group conflict expressed by Realistic Group Conflict Theory can be informed by elements within Resource Dependence Theory, and present Resource Uncertainly Conflict Theory (RUCT) as a plausible synthesis of the two views. Specifically, our model specifies the conditions under which group interaction will lead to competitive or collaborative behavior and thus the intensity of conflict experienced by the groups. The antecedents are resource uncertainty, performance based rewards, and a
supraordinate goal, with the first two antecedents adopted from RGCT and resource uncertainly comprised of three dimensions informed RDT as salient to groups and not conceptually misaligned with RGCT. Our model links resource uncertainty with competition via bidirectional arrows; we propose that uncertainly over environmental resources increases the risk of competition rather than cooperation, which is then more likely to lead to conflict and consequently further heighten uncertainty over a now openly-disputed resource. Competition is our proposed mediator, which is posited to lead to conflict, moderated by the degree of power asymmetry, power concentration and outside system control, three structural variables impacting on conflict according to the RDT perspective. Thus, our antecedent elements encompass the outside environment, while the mediator and moderator relate more specifically to social interdependence with regard to environmental resources.
Figure 1
is explicitly intra-organizational), we do not intend to limit the future application of RUCM to the organizational context.
Resource Importance
Ultimately, survival is the goal of most if not all organic entities, with organizational groups and teams being no exception. In a competitive business landscape, where strong in- group and out-group distinctions have formed due to dependence on outside resources, rewards based on performance, and the absence of a supraordinate goal, the emergence of conflict will depend in part on the level of uncertainty over a needed resource. When the level of uncertainty is high – because the resource is important – we propose that competition will more likely emerge between the interdependent groups because a zero-sum relationship will be more rewarding for the group that can establish power and dominance, leading to eventual conflict between the groups.
Proposition 1 : Under conditions of resource importance, performance-based rewards, and no supra-ordinate goal, interdependent groups are more likely to compete rather than cooperate, thereby leading to conflict.
Resource Scarcity In terms of inter-group collaboration, when two groups depend on a scarce resource for existence, they are more likely to adopt a competitive stance because interdependency would be less mutually beneficial. When the supply of a needed resource is limited, its acquisition becomes more uncertain, as other groups in demand of such resource are likely to adapt their behavior to gain control over it to assure their own survival. Thus, we predict that resource
scarcity will more likely lead to competition (and eventual conflict) between interdependent groups.
Proposition 2: Under conditions of resource scarcity, performance-based rewards, and no supra-ordinate goal, interdependent groups are more likely to compete rather than cooperate, thereby leading to conflict.
Availability of Alternates According to Pfeffer and Salancik (1978), when alternatives to a resource are available, interactions between firms will likely be less competitive because the alternatives provide a means of survival when the resource is no longer available. In such cases, the inability to secure a desired resource is less of a threat to the survival of the group or organization, because it can be obtained elsewhere and/or in a different form. However, when there is no other alternative to the desired resource, the competition between the groups will likely turn to conflict because the relationship evolves into a zero-sum game. Thus, we predict that under competitive conditions, a lack of availability of alternates will lead to conflict between interdependent groups.
Proposition 3: Under conditions of a lack of available alternatives, performance-based rewards, and no supra-ordinate goal, interdependent groups are more likely to compete rather than cooperate, thereby leading to conflict.
Concentration According to Pfeffer and Salancik (1978), when power is concentrated among fewer organizations, inter-organizational coordination becomes easier because there are fewer actors to deal with and thus the overall level of environmental uncertainly is reduced. However, we contend that the concentration of power between two interdependent groups may be expressed in multiple ways (i.e., multiple resources may be involved) and thus we propose concentration as a
over a particular resource but relates instead to the broader outside network. We thus apply system control as a moderator rather than an antecedent of intergroup conflict. We expect that a competitive relationship between two groups will more likely lead to conflict between such groups when there is a high degree of outside system control.
Proposition 6 Under conditions of high system control over environmental resources, conflict will be increased between competitive interdependent groups.
Implications for Theory and Practice
The proposed model has several implications for future theory and practice. First, in terms of its implications for scholarship, it provides a more comprehensive perspective for understanding and predicting inter-group conflict. The model identifies three dimensions of resource uncertainty as antecedents of conflict that are not accounted for by current micro and meso theories. This is an important contribution because it connects what we already know about inter-firm relationships to areas of intra-firm relations that prior research has not yet examined. Thus, the proposed model represents the synthesis of the micro, meso, and macro theories of inter-group conflict and creates the foundation for a more informed view of the multi-level factors leading to inter-group conflict.
Our proposed RUCM model is a key contribution because it synthesizes existing theories from multiple domains and levels of structural analysis and seeks to integrate them into a more usable and inclusive conceptual framework for use in future research. Theoretically, our model serves as a bridge aimed at assimilating and organizing currently disjointed and fragmented perspectives on the same topic into a more cohesive and useful model. Our approach undertakes to link seemingly unconnected theories that we believe complement rather than contradict one
another, focusing on shared aspects of commonality. Taken together, our proposed model could provide a more complete understanding of interorganizational conflict than any one perspective alone, and potentially identifies new paths for research in this domain.
There are several other ways that the model proposed here could be extended to include and potentially explain phenomena outside of organizational conflict. One natural extension of the model is to the literature on social movements. For instance, many existing theories on social movements are concerned with examining the structural conditions that predicate social unrest and revolution. Just as the model explained here integrates theories relating to group conflict within organizations at multiple levels, it could also be potentially useful to apply the same integrative logic to theories that describe the process by which collective action is ignited. It is likely that forces at multiple levels (i.e. micro, meso, and macro) act on groups with any type of social or political agenda as well. Thus, there is nothing inherent to organizations that would present a likely or substantial difference enough to alter the explanation of intergroup behavior proposed here.
Another potential extension of the model is to the realm of cyberculture. As the Internet and social media continue to revolutionize the way we communicate in all spheres of life and disrupt incumbent businesses and governmental structures alike (e.g., the Arab Spring movement of 2010/2011), it is imperative to better grasp the conditions under which conflict arises, spreads, and dissipates on digital platforms. While the Internet allows for individuals to communicate and form groups more quickly and informally than has been possible in prior generations, we remain bound to the same biological imperatives and sociocultural influences. Thus, our proposed integrative model of conflict may provide a useful mechanism to approach the